David Gauthier
- Published in print:
- 1987
- Published Online:
- November 2003
- ISBN:
- 9780198249924
- eISBN:
- 9780191597497
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/0198249926.003.0004
- Subject:
- Philosophy, Moral Philosophy
Economics celebrates an ideal of interaction free from all constraint, an ideal found in the perfectly competitive market, where equilibrium and optimality coincide. Morality can then be thought of ...
More
Economics celebrates an ideal of interaction free from all constraint, an ideal found in the perfectly competitive market, where equilibrium and optimality coincide. Morality can then be thought of as arising from market failure; the perfect market itself operates as a morally free zone, because the only behaviour it makes possible excludes those features of natural interaction that prevent individuals, each acting to maximize his own utility, from achieving optimality. We examine the conditions for market success—individual factor endowments, free individual activity, private goods, mutual unconcern, and the absence of all externalities—showing that these extend the freedom of the solitary individual to the context of interaction, and exclude all free‐riding, parasitism, and any form of partiality. But we note that the initial factor endowment of each person, taken as a given in market interaction, is itself subject to rational and moral scrutiny (a matter examined in Ch. 7). The chapter concludes with a discussion of utilitarian and Marxist objections to the market, both of which we reject.Less
Economics celebrates an ideal of interaction free from all constraint, an ideal found in the perfectly competitive market, where equilibrium and optimality coincide. Morality can then be thought of as arising from market failure; the perfect market itself operates as a morally free zone, because the only behaviour it makes possible excludes those features of natural interaction that prevent individuals, each acting to maximize his own utility, from achieving optimality. We examine the conditions for market success—individual factor endowments, free individual activity, private goods, mutual unconcern, and the absence of all externalities—showing that these extend the freedom of the solitary individual to the context of interaction, and exclude all free‐riding, parasitism, and any form of partiality. But we note that the initial factor endowment of each person, taken as a given in market interaction, is itself subject to rational and moral scrutiny (a matter examined in Ch. 7). The chapter concludes with a discussion of utilitarian and Marxist objections to the market, both of which we reject.
Cristiano Antonelli
- Published in print:
- 2012
- Published Online:
- January 2013
- ISBN:
- 9780199646685
- eISBN:
- 9780191748998
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199646685.003.0010
- Subject:
- Economics and Finance, Financial Economics
This chapter opens up for new perspectives on how to understand the development and the choice of technology solutions by distinguishing between (i) moving the best practice frontier downwards and ...
More
This chapter opens up for new perspectives on how to understand the development and the choice of technology solutions by distinguishing between (i) moving the best practice frontier downwards and (ii) settling on a specific factor combination (specific factor ratio). As a matter of fact, higher levels of efficiency can be obtained with two distinct forms of technological change: i) neutral technological change consisting in general and symmetric shift of the map of the isoquants towards the origin; and ii) biased technological change that consists in asymmetric change of the form of the isoquants. In the latter case efficiency gains are obtained because of higher levels of congruence between the local factor markets and the output elasticity of production factors. The main idea is that an economy, at the aggregate level, as well each firm, industry and region, are rewarded if it manages to choose factor proportions that are congruent with localized resource composition, such that e.g. labor abundant economies apply labor intensive technology solutions.Less
This chapter opens up for new perspectives on how to understand the development and the choice of technology solutions by distinguishing between (i) moving the best practice frontier downwards and (ii) settling on a specific factor combination (specific factor ratio). As a matter of fact, higher levels of efficiency can be obtained with two distinct forms of technological change: i) neutral technological change consisting in general and symmetric shift of the map of the isoquants towards the origin; and ii) biased technological change that consists in asymmetric change of the form of the isoquants. In the latter case efficiency gains are obtained because of higher levels of congruence between the local factor markets and the output elasticity of production factors. The main idea is that an economy, at the aggregate level, as well each firm, industry and region, are rewarded if it manages to choose factor proportions that are congruent with localized resource composition, such that e.g. labor abundant economies apply labor intensive technology solutions.
David Gauthier
- Published in print:
- 1987
- Published Online:
- November 2003
- ISBN:
- 9780198249924
- eISBN:
- 9780191597497
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/0198249926.003.0007
- Subject:
- Philosophy, Moral Philosophy
Takes up the questions of the initial bargaining position and the initial factor endowment, raised in Chs. 6 and 4 respectively. We reject James Buchanan's identification of the initial bargaining ...
More
Takes up the questions of the initial bargaining position and the initial factor endowment, raised in Chs. 6 and 4 respectively. We reject James Buchanan's identification of the initial bargaining position with the outcome of non‐cooperative interaction, and John Harsanyi's identification of it with the threat point. Instead, we argue that, as the basis of market and cooperative interaction, it must rule out all taking of advantage—bettering oneself through worsening the situation of others. We term this condition the ‘proviso’, deriving it from Robert Nozick's interpretation of Locke's insistence that in acquisition, one leave ‘enough, and as good’ for others. We show how the proviso constrains directly maximizing behaviour, and we then demonstrate its role in introducing a structure of individual rights to person and property, rights that define each person's initial bargaining position and factor endowment. We show that the proviso satisfies our standard of impartiality, and why rational persons would accept the proviso, as part of a narrow interpretation of compliance with the requirements for cooperation. We show that cooperation in the absence of the proviso tends to be unstable, and to depend on ideologies, entrenched historical factors, and differential technologies, all of which undermine the equal rationality of persons on which an impartial morality depends.Less
Takes up the questions of the initial bargaining position and the initial factor endowment, raised in Chs. 6 and 4 respectively. We reject James Buchanan's identification of the initial bargaining position with the outcome of non‐cooperative interaction, and John Harsanyi's identification of it with the threat point. Instead, we argue that, as the basis of market and cooperative interaction, it must rule out all taking of advantage—bettering oneself through worsening the situation of others. We term this condition the ‘proviso’, deriving it from Robert Nozick's interpretation of Locke's insistence that in acquisition, one leave ‘enough, and as good’ for others. We show how the proviso constrains directly maximizing behaviour, and we then demonstrate its role in introducing a structure of individual rights to person and property, rights that define each person's initial bargaining position and factor endowment. We show that the proviso satisfies our standard of impartiality, and why rational persons would accept the proviso, as part of a narrow interpretation of compliance with the requirements for cooperation. We show that cooperation in the absence of the proviso tends to be unstable, and to depend on ideologies, entrenched historical factors, and differential technologies, all of which undermine the equal rationality of persons on which an impartial morality depends.
Leigh A. Gardner
- Published in print:
- 2012
- Published Online:
- January 2013
- ISBN:
- 9780199661527
- eISBN:
- 9780191744877
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199661527.003.0002
- Subject:
- History, Economic History, British and Irish Modern History
This chapter places the financial management of the British Empire in historical perspective by examining how empires through history have weighted the desire to acquire new territory against the ...
More
This chapter places the financial management of the British Empire in historical perspective by examining how empires through history have weighted the desire to acquire new territory against the costs of governing it. It reviews the methods used by the British government to manage the rising costs of colonial expansion from its very earliest years until the twentieth century, focusing on the specific challenges created by the Scramble for Africa in the late nineteenth century. Chartered companies played an important role as agents of imperial expansion, but often failed when the costs of governing their new territories exceeded the profits of colonial trade. This was particularly true in Africa, where factor endowments of abundant land and scarce labour provided a very limited tax base with which to support colonial administrations. Efforts to minimize costs resulted in colonial administrations with limited manpower, and the use of indirect rule through African elites.Less
This chapter places the financial management of the British Empire in historical perspective by examining how empires through history have weighted the desire to acquire new territory against the costs of governing it. It reviews the methods used by the British government to manage the rising costs of colonial expansion from its very earliest years until the twentieth century, focusing on the specific challenges created by the Scramble for Africa in the late nineteenth century. Chartered companies played an important role as agents of imperial expansion, but often failed when the costs of governing their new territories exceeded the profits of colonial trade. This was particularly true in Africa, where factor endowments of abundant land and scarce labour provided a very limited tax base with which to support colonial administrations. Efforts to minimize costs resulted in colonial administrations with limited manpower, and the use of indirect rule through African elites.
David Gauthier
- Published in print:
- 1987
- Published Online:
- November 2003
- ISBN:
- 9780198249924
- eISBN:
- 9780191597497
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/0198249926.003.0005
- Subject:
- Philosophy, Moral Philosophy
In this chapter, we turn to cooperation as the remedy for market failure, and to justice as the rational disposition to cooperative behaviour. Instead of each person choosing her own strategy, in ...
More
In this chapter, we turn to cooperation as the remedy for market failure, and to justice as the rational disposition to cooperative behaviour. Instead of each person choosing her own strategy, in cooperation persons agree on a single joint strategy choice leading to an optimal outcome. We argue that such a choice results from an ideal bargain among all persons, and offer an account of bargaining, in terms of the initial bargaining position, the claims rational persons would make from that position, and the concessions they would then offer to achieve agreement on a joint strategy, yielding a fundamental principle labelled ‘minimax relative concession’. We then show that this principle is equivalent to ‘maximin relative benefit’, in which the smallest gain anyone receives, measured as a proportion of the gain he would receive from being granted his claim, is as great as possible. The principle of maximin relative benefit, we claim, captures the idea of impartiality in the distribution of the benefits of cooperation, and so is a principle of fairness or justice. Thus, rational bargaining and justice coincide. But we note that the question of determining the initial bargaining position remains to be resolved, both rationally and morally; this question is in fact the same as that of determining initial factor endowments, which we raised and deferred in the previous chapter.Less
In this chapter, we turn to cooperation as the remedy for market failure, and to justice as the rational disposition to cooperative behaviour. Instead of each person choosing her own strategy, in cooperation persons agree on a single joint strategy choice leading to an optimal outcome. We argue that such a choice results from an ideal bargain among all persons, and offer an account of bargaining, in terms of the initial bargaining position, the claims rational persons would make from that position, and the concessions they would then offer to achieve agreement on a joint strategy, yielding a fundamental principle labelled ‘minimax relative concession’. We then show that this principle is equivalent to ‘maximin relative benefit’, in which the smallest gain anyone receives, measured as a proportion of the gain he would receive from being granted his claim, is as great as possible. The principle of maximin relative benefit, we claim, captures the idea of impartiality in the distribution of the benefits of cooperation, and so is a principle of fairness or justice. Thus, rational bargaining and justice coincide. But we note that the question of determining the initial bargaining position remains to be resolved, both rationally and morally; this question is in fact the same as that of determining initial factor endowments, which we raised and deferred in the previous chapter.
Kevin Hjortshøj O’Rourke and Jeffrey Gale Williamson
- Published in print:
- 2017
- Published Online:
- March 2017
- ISBN:
- 9780198753643
- eISBN:
- 9780191815232
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198753643.003.0001
- Subject:
- History, Economic History, World Modern History
The fact that modern industry originated in Britain, and spread initially to Northwest Europe and North America, implied a dramatic divergence in living standards between the industrial ‘West’ and a ...
More
The fact that modern industry originated in Britain, and spread initially to Northwest Europe and North America, implied a dramatic divergence in living standards between the industrial ‘West’ and a non-industrial ‘Rest’. This industrial divergence is visibly unravelling today, as Third World economies converge industrially on the rich economies of Europe and North America. This phenomenon has been the subject of much research. Less appreciated, however, are the deep historical roots of this convergence, and in particular of the spread of modern industry to the global periphery. This chapter provides an introduction to the book, which fills this gap by providing a systematic, comparative, historical account of the spread of modern manufacturing beyond its traditional heartland to what we call the poor periphery. The chapter highlights the roles of factor endowments, the international context, luck, and economic policy in determining the timing and extent of manufacturing growth.Less
The fact that modern industry originated in Britain, and spread initially to Northwest Europe and North America, implied a dramatic divergence in living standards between the industrial ‘West’ and a non-industrial ‘Rest’. This industrial divergence is visibly unravelling today, as Third World economies converge industrially on the rich economies of Europe and North America. This phenomenon has been the subject of much research. Less appreciated, however, are the deep historical roots of this convergence, and in particular of the spread of modern industry to the global periphery. This chapter provides an introduction to the book, which fills this gap by providing a systematic, comparative, historical account of the spread of modern manufacturing beyond its traditional heartland to what we call the poor periphery. The chapter highlights the roles of factor endowments, the international context, luck, and economic policy in determining the timing and extent of manufacturing growth.
Mthuli Ncube and Charles Leyeka Lufumpa (eds)
- Published in print:
- 2017
- Published Online:
- September 2017
- ISBN:
- 9781447326632
- eISBN:
- 9781447326663
- Item type:
- book
- Publisher:
- Policy Press
- DOI:
- 10.1332/policypress/9781447326632.001.0001
- Subject:
- Political Science, Comparative Politics
There is a widespread recognition that Africa has to embark on strategies for sustainable and inclusive development. African economies have to evolve in their levels of development including the ...
More
There is a widespread recognition that Africa has to embark on strategies for sustainable and inclusive development. African economies have to evolve in their levels of development including the associated structure of factor endowments. However, each such structure requires corresponding infrastructure (both “hard” and “soft”) to circumscribe its operations and transactions. The type of infrastructure which is needed and what type of infrastructure would work for sustainable development more than others needs to be delineated. This book gives a sense of what exist and what Africa really needs in terms of its infrastructure. The contributors explore the challenges and opportunities for infrastructure development in Africa to take cognisance of and ensure balance between ‘what should be the case’ and ‘what is’. The book considers a wide range of pertinent issues such as corruption, tight budgets (RBM) and poor incentives that bred the tendency for poor maintenance and infrastructure service delivery and the subsequent deterioration of business confidence and related private sector engagement. Indeed, the arrival of other players such as China presents not just opportunities but also challenges for the development of infrastructure (in particular) and Africa (in general).Less
There is a widespread recognition that Africa has to embark on strategies for sustainable and inclusive development. African economies have to evolve in their levels of development including the associated structure of factor endowments. However, each such structure requires corresponding infrastructure (both “hard” and “soft”) to circumscribe its operations and transactions. The type of infrastructure which is needed and what type of infrastructure would work for sustainable development more than others needs to be delineated. This book gives a sense of what exist and what Africa really needs in terms of its infrastructure. The contributors explore the challenges and opportunities for infrastructure development in Africa to take cognisance of and ensure balance between ‘what should be the case’ and ‘what is’. The book considers a wide range of pertinent issues such as corruption, tight budgets (RBM) and poor incentives that bred the tendency for poor maintenance and infrastructure service delivery and the subsequent deterioration of business confidence and related private sector engagement. Indeed, the arrival of other players such as China presents not just opportunities but also challenges for the development of infrastructure (in particular) and Africa (in general).
Gareth Austin, Ewout Frankema, and Morten Jerven
- Published in print:
- 2017
- Published Online:
- March 2017
- ISBN:
- 9780198753643
- eISBN:
- 9780191815232
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198753643.003.0014
- Subject:
- History, Economic History, World Modern History
This chapter reviews the ‘long twentieth-century’ development of ‘modern’ manufacturing in Sub-Saharan Africa from colonization to the present. It argues that classifying Africa generically as a ...
More
This chapter reviews the ‘long twentieth-century’ development of ‘modern’ manufacturing in Sub-Saharan Africa from colonization to the present. It argues that classifying Africa generically as a ‘late industrializer’ is inaccurate. To understand the distinctively African pattern of manufacturing growth, the discussion focuses on the dynamic interplay between the region’s specific endowment structures, global economic relationships, and government policies. It concludes that Sub-Saharan Africa is best characterized as a case of interrupted industrial growth instead of sustained convergence on world industrial leaders. This is partly because, until very recently, factor endowments made it very costly for states to pursue industrialization; and partly because successive rulers, colonial and post-colonial, have rarely had both the capacity to adopt and the dedication to sustain policies that modified the region’s existing comparative advantage in primary production, by using their fiscal and regulatory powers effectively to promote industrialization.Less
This chapter reviews the ‘long twentieth-century’ development of ‘modern’ manufacturing in Sub-Saharan Africa from colonization to the present. It argues that classifying Africa generically as a ‘late industrializer’ is inaccurate. To understand the distinctively African pattern of manufacturing growth, the discussion focuses on the dynamic interplay between the region’s specific endowment structures, global economic relationships, and government policies. It concludes that Sub-Saharan Africa is best characterized as a case of interrupted industrial growth instead of sustained convergence on world industrial leaders. This is partly because, until very recently, factor endowments made it very costly for states to pursue industrialization; and partly because successive rulers, colonial and post-colonial, have rarely had both the capacity to adopt and the dedication to sustain policies that modified the region’s existing comparative advantage in primary production, by using their fiscal and regulatory powers effectively to promote industrialization.
Bumba Mukherjee
- Published in print:
- 2016
- Published Online:
- January 2017
- ISBN:
- 9780226358789
- eISBN:
- 9780226358956
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- University of Chicago Press
- DOI:
- 10.7208/chicago/9780226358956.003.0002
- Subject:
- Political Science, International Relations and Politics
This chapter starts by providing the foundation for the book’s central theoretical model that explores the link between democratization and trade reforms in developing countries. The chapter builds ...
More
This chapter starts by providing the foundation for the book’s central theoretical model that explores the link between democratization and trade reforms in developing countries. The chapter builds on this foundation to understand how political competition over office by political parties in the context of new democratic institutions affects trade policy given certain labor market conditions. The theoretical model then uses the logic of game-theory to analyze how labor market conditions affects the domestic balance of political power between labor and capital in a newly democratized regime and how this in turn influences the design of trade policy by political parties (including the ruling party) in this regime. The model is then extended to understand when and how the adoption of trade reforms in new democracies may decrease the likelihood of electoral malpractices in these regimes and thus foster democratic consolidation.Less
This chapter starts by providing the foundation for the book’s central theoretical model that explores the link between democratization and trade reforms in developing countries. The chapter builds on this foundation to understand how political competition over office by political parties in the context of new democratic institutions affects trade policy given certain labor market conditions. The theoretical model then uses the logic of game-theory to analyze how labor market conditions affects the domestic balance of political power between labor and capital in a newly democratized regime and how this in turn influences the design of trade policy by political parties (including the ruling party) in this regime. The model is then extended to understand when and how the adoption of trade reforms in new democracies may decrease the likelihood of electoral malpractices in these regimes and thus foster democratic consolidation.
Ulaş Karakoç, Şevket Pamuk, and Laura Panza
- Published in print:
- 2017
- Published Online:
- March 2017
- ISBN:
- 9780198753643
- eISBN:
- 9780191815232
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198753643.003.0007
- Subject:
- History, Economic History, World Modern History
This chapter examines the industrial performance of Egypt and Turkey during four periods: 1870 to the First World War under open economy conditions; the inter-war era when industrialization began ...
More
This chapter examines the industrial performance of Egypt and Turkey during four periods: 1870 to the First World War under open economy conditions; the inter-war era when industrialization began with the help of protection; the decades after the Second World War when the import-substituting industrialization model was adopted and rates of industrialization peaked; and trade liberalization since 1980. Per capita incomes were similar in Egypt and Turkey around 1870 but were 150 per cent higher in Turkey than in Egypt in 2010. The chapter identifies several factors which explain this divergence: land abundance in Turkey and its scarcity in Egypt; initial social structure and related political economy forces; government intervention; and the quality of related institutions. In terms of human capital investment, Turkey and Egypt lagged behind countries in Latin America and East Asia, which made it difficult for manufacturing to move towards sectors with higher technology and value added.Less
This chapter examines the industrial performance of Egypt and Turkey during four periods: 1870 to the First World War under open economy conditions; the inter-war era when industrialization began with the help of protection; the decades after the Second World War when the import-substituting industrialization model was adopted and rates of industrialization peaked; and trade liberalization since 1980. Per capita incomes were similar in Egypt and Turkey around 1870 but were 150 per cent higher in Turkey than in Egypt in 2010. The chapter identifies several factors which explain this divergence: land abundance in Turkey and its scarcity in Egypt; initial social structure and related political economy forces; government intervention; and the quality of related institutions. In terms of human capital investment, Turkey and Egypt lagged behind countries in Latin America and East Asia, which made it difficult for manufacturing to move towards sectors with higher technology and value added.
Jean-Pascal Bassino and Jeffrey Gale Williamson
- Published in print:
- 2017
- Published Online:
- March 2017
- ISBN:
- 9780198753643
- eISBN:
- 9780191815232
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198753643.003.0011
- Subject:
- History, Economic History, World Modern History
Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand emerged unexpectedly in the 1960s and 1970s as fast-growing, labour-intensive manufacturing countries. Their industrial growth rates closely matched those of Japan, ...
More
Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand emerged unexpectedly in the 1960s and 1970s as fast-growing, labour-intensive manufacturing countries. Their industrial growth rates closely matched those of Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan for more than two decades. This sudden export-led ‘miracle’ took place in the context of political instability and ethnic tensions, after more than two decades of modest success with post-independence, import-substituting industrialization strategies there and in other Southeast Asian nations. Cambodia and Vietnam joined the export-led manufacturing club in the 1990s, followed by Myanmar in the 2000s. The Philippines was the only Southeast Asian nation to miss the late twentieth-century ‘miracle’. Southeast Asia experienced some impressive GDP per capita growth between 1870 and 1940, but, outside of the Philippines, manufacturing stagnated and modern enterprises were confined to commodity export processing. The chapter analyses the region’s dismal industrial performance before the 1960s, and why manufacturing grew so fast in the following decades.Less
Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand emerged unexpectedly in the 1960s and 1970s as fast-growing, labour-intensive manufacturing countries. Their industrial growth rates closely matched those of Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan for more than two decades. This sudden export-led ‘miracle’ took place in the context of political instability and ethnic tensions, after more than two decades of modest success with post-independence, import-substituting industrialization strategies there and in other Southeast Asian nations. Cambodia and Vietnam joined the export-led manufacturing club in the 1990s, followed by Myanmar in the 2000s. The Philippines was the only Southeast Asian nation to miss the late twentieth-century ‘miracle’. Southeast Asia experienced some impressive GDP per capita growth between 1870 and 1940, but, outside of the Philippines, manufacturing stagnated and modern enterprises were confined to commodity export processing. The chapter analyses the region’s dismal industrial performance before the 1960s, and why manufacturing grew so fast in the following decades.
Aurora Gómez-Galvarriato and Graciela Márquez Colín
- Published in print:
- 2017
- Published Online:
- March 2017
- ISBN:
- 9780198753643
- eISBN:
- 9780191815232
- Item type:
- chapter
- Publisher:
- Oxford University Press
- DOI:
- 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198753643.003.0012
- Subject:
- History, Economic History, World Modern History
The industrialization experiences of Mexico and Peru differed because of their different market sizes and location. Mexico’s larger market and border with the US gave it greater opportunities for ...
More
The industrialization experiences of Mexico and Peru differed because of their different market sizes and location. Mexico’s larger market and border with the US gave it greater opportunities for industrialization. Peru’s development is closer to that of the classic late-nineteenth-century commodity exporter and followed the primary-goods-exports model for longer. Until the 1980s both countries had relatively high wages, inhibiting the development of labour-intensive manufactured exports, but they lacked the education and skill levels to produce more technologically sophisticated manufacturing goods. Contrary to common belief, commodity export-led growth supported industrial growth as long as exports were diversified and the government pursued sound fiscal and monetary policies. Import substitution policies fostered manufacturing growth when coupled with macroeconomic stability and policies promoting domestic and foreign investment. After economic liberalization in recent decades, Peru returned to relying on commodity exports, while Mexico developed assembly export manufacturing, with very low levels of domestic value added.Less
The industrialization experiences of Mexico and Peru differed because of their different market sizes and location. Mexico’s larger market and border with the US gave it greater opportunities for industrialization. Peru’s development is closer to that of the classic late-nineteenth-century commodity exporter and followed the primary-goods-exports model for longer. Until the 1980s both countries had relatively high wages, inhibiting the development of labour-intensive manufactured exports, but they lacked the education and skill levels to produce more technologically sophisticated manufacturing goods. Contrary to common belief, commodity export-led growth supported industrial growth as long as exports were diversified and the government pursued sound fiscal and monetary policies. Import substitution policies fostered manufacturing growth when coupled with macroeconomic stability and policies promoting domestic and foreign investment. After economic liberalization in recent decades, Peru returned to relying on commodity exports, while Mexico developed assembly export manufacturing, with very low levels of domestic value added.